[T]he superstition that the budget must be balanced at all times, once it is debunked, takes away one of the bulwarks that every society must have against expenditure out of control. . . . [O]ne of the functions of old-fashioned religion was to scare people by sometimes what might be regarded as myths into behaving in a way that long-run civilized life requires.
Tuesday, August 05, 2014
Thoughts on rent control
I want to start by noting, as mentioned in the article, that economists do not consider rent control as just an example of an undesirable price ceiling, but as a canonical example. There are many other potential examples, such as gas prices in the 1970s, or Nixon's wage and price ceilings, but economists haved picked rent control as the example as the best teaching tool to show that price ceilings are socially undesirable. Thus, we can look at the article first as criticizing this pedagogical choice. If removing rent control in typical, real-world situations does not typically result in increasing social welfare, but merely transfers surplus from consumers to suppliers, then it is a poor pedagogical tool, akin to trying to teach gravity by having students think about the behavior of airplanes (which do not, of course, fall when you drop them). In this regard, I think the authors succeed.
But I want to take a closer look at price ceilings in general. In general, economists talk about consumer and producer surplus. For consumers, this surplus is getting some good or service for less than they would have paid. I really love beer, for example. I would spend \$5 on the first beer of the day, but all my beer costs \$0.50. For my first beer, I'm getting \$4.50 of "surplus." For producers, the surplus is the difference between the marginal cost and the price. The brewery can make some of its beers for only \$0.45, so they're getting \$0.05 of surplus on those beers. (They sell a lot more beer than I drink, so that the \$0.05 adds up quickly.) We show this concept like this:
The shaded areas represent "surplus", a.k.a. "welfare", benefits that the consumers and producers get "for free". It is generally accepted that, absent externalities (people who gain or lose who are neither producers nor consumers of the good) and transaction costs (costs paid by the consumer that do not benefit the producer), the point where the (marginal) supply and demand curves meet, the market price, represents the price and quantity that maximize total welfare (consumer surplus + producer surplus).
Rent control is commonly modeled as a price ceiling, where the government arbitrarily sets a price for a good below the market price.
The canonical model of a price ceiling looks like this:
Here, the government has set a price ceiling, Pc. Because we don't force firms to produce at a loss, firms produce a smaller quantity if they can sell only at the price ceiling. Some of the welfare is redistributed from producers to consumers, but more importantly, some trade is just lost; welfare just vanishes. This lost welfare is labeled "Deadweight Loss" is the graph. At higher prices, producers are willing to produce goods, and consumers are willing to buy them, but the price ceiling prevents these welfare-generating trades. Economists see this loss of welfare as a Bad Thing, and thus argue against price ceilings.
Note too that at the restricted quantities, enough consumers are willing to pay a lot more, the "black market price" (Pb), than even the market price. This willingness can lead to illegality and corruption. Also, at the price ceiling, a lot more consumers are willing to buy (Qb) but cannot. Price ceilings can lead to a lot of problems all around.
But, like all economic graphs, the graphs above lie: specifically, they make assumptions about the supply and demand curves that are not always (indeed rarely) true, notably that they have a slope of about +/-1. I argue that in many cases, in the short term, the absolute value of slope of the supply and demand curves for rental housing is much larger than one, i.e. both are relatively inelastic.* The reason is that in the short term, i.e. holding the level of capital constant, we cannot build new buildings (since new buildings represent new capital). Thus, when there is increased demand, all we can do is use labor, a lot of labor, to rehabilitate the few older buildings back into economic use. Furthermore, there are cities, such as New York or San Francisco, where people will pay a lot to live there, especially at the margin (i.e. a new person coming to the city will pay a lot to move there). Hence, a small shift in the demand curve, such as when Google decides to add a thousand new engineers, whom they can pay enough to cover any rent increases, can have a dramatic impact on the market.
*Note that unless we're using a log scale, the slopes of curves do not directly represent elasticity, which is percentage change in the dependent variable per percentage change in the independent variable, which depends not only on the slope but the level. But slope is a pretty good proxy for elasticity.
I look at rental markets like this:
(Note that my graph is too small to show the short run quantity, which is between Qe and Qlr.)
Here, a small shift in the demand curve, from D to D' causes a large increase in the short run market price. I'm obviously oversimplifying here: e.g. not all rental housing is alike, but I think the graph gets the basic point across.
There is a perfectly good neoclassical economic argument that the government should do something here; the market, by itself, is insufficient to achieve the socially optimal outcome. The story includes the enormous transaction costs associated with moving, especially to a different city. The story goes like this: Google hires a thousand engineers, causing a shift in the demand curve. Rent goes to Psr, pricing a lot of people out of the rental market, people who could afford to pay the long run rent, Plr, and the city fills up with people who can afford to pay the short run rent. In the long run, rent decreases to the long run level, but people who could have paid that rent are long gone. Hence we incur wasteful transaction costs because of the short- and long-run disparity in rent. The government could prevent these wasteful transaction costs by imposing a price ceiling on existing rents (where no additional cost is necessary to bring the property into service), letting them rise to the long-run level, but not to the short-run level. New residents, who can afford it, pay the short run price in the short run, but eventually pay the long-run rent. This is, essentially, what most rent control regimes actually do.
Second, there's a political economy argument. We do not live in a laissez faire political economy; we live in a capitalist political economy, where people who own capital have political control. Furthermore, residential real estate is fundamentally different from an ordinary firm. The present value of any business is the discounted expected income stream of the business. For example, if my business runs a profit of \$100000 per year, and I discount future income at 2.5% per year, then the value of the business is $100000*∑↙{n=0}↖∞ (1-0.025)^n = $\$4 million. A normal business (like a sandwich shop or automobile manufacturer) has to actually be operating to have an expected income stream; the expected income of a closed sandwich shop is 0. However, real estate does not have to operate to have an expected income stream. An occupied and an unoccupied building have about the same value. A building owner can realize the value of his building just by borrowing against it (and paying minimal maintenance costs) rather than letting nasty tenants poop in the toilets. In a depressed economy, buying a building and leaving it empty is a viable investment scheme, as long as few enough people actually do it.
Building owners, then, have a double incentive to enact supply limits (shortages), both market-based and just by taking property off the market, to essentially make the long-run supply curve match the short-run supply curve, essentially creating a quota (which works the same as a price ceiling, except the producers expropriate surplus from the consumers).
Again, rent control can mitigate this market failure both by limiting the incentive to create shortages and by forcing buildings to be occupied to be valuable.
So... that, I think, is why rent control is a bad illustration of a quota, and why rent control is a Good Thing when both demand and supply are highly inelastic in a particular market.
7 comments:
Please pick a handle or moniker for your comment. It's much easier to address someone by a name or pseudonym than simply "hey you". I have the option of requiring a "hard" identity, but I don't want to turn that on... yet.
With few exceptions, I will not respond or reply to anonymous comments, and I may delete them. I keep a copy of all comments; if you want the text of your comment to repost with something vaguely resembling an identity, email me.
No spam, pr0n, commercial advertising, insanity, lies, repetition or off-topic comments. Creationists, Global Warming deniers, anti-vaxers, Randians, and Libertarians are automatically presumed to be idiots; Christians and Muslims might get the benefit of the doubt, if I'm in a good mood.
See the Debate Flowchart for some basic rules.
Sourced factual corrections are always published and acknowledged.
I will respond or not respond to comments as the mood takes me. See my latest comment policy for details. I am not a pseudonomous-American: my real name is Larry.
Comments may be moderated from time to time. When I do moderate comments, anonymous comments are far more likely to be rejected.
I've already answered some typical comments.
I have jqMath enabled for the blog. If you have a dollar sign (\$) in your comment, put a \\ in front of it: \\\$, unless you want to include a formula in your comment.
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.
(I left a comment yesterday but it's presumed lost.)
ReplyDeleteI fully admit the value of rent control to stabilize short run fluctuations in prices. However, people here see rent control as a way of mitigating gentrification, and gentrification is of course a long-term trend. I believe in this case, the benefit of rent control is limiting transaction costs by preventing people from having to move, switch jobs, etc.
I think, here in the SF bay area, the problem is not so much with the economics of rent control, but with the politics of it. Ideally, the short run increase in rents should signal that more housing is needed, and since new housing developments are not rent-controlled, rent control does not interfere with this. In practice, SF is simultaneously limiting new housing development through zoning restrictions. The zoning restrictions are maintained by incumbent tenants, who talk about "preserving the character" of their neighborhoods (ie against the spectre of gentrification). Prospective tenants, of course, don't have the power to vote on city regulations.
I don't entirely understand the second argument. While a quota would increase the total surplus to landlords, creating that quota requires individual landlords to take their units off the market, thus sacrificing any share of the surplus they might get.
(I left a comment yesterday but it's presumed lost.)
DeleteThere's nothing in the spam folder or on email. I don't know what happened.
However, people here see rent control as a way of mitigating gentrification, and gentrification is of course a long-term trend.
ReplyDeleteIt's been a while since I've lived in SF, so I will take your word for it here. But if so, so what? If people want something, and they are paying for it, then why is resistance to gentrification per se bad?
Ideally, the short run increase in rents should signal that more housing is needed, and since new housing developments are not rent-controlled, rent control does not interfere with this.
Indeed.
The zoning restrictions are maintained by incumbent tenants, who talk about "preserving the character" of their neighborhoods
Again, that's a political issue. If that's what they want, that's what they want.
Prospective tenants, of course, don't have the power to vote on city regulations.
Nope. First come, first serve: a time-honored principle. I don't think there's a good way around it.
While a quota would increase the total surplus to landlords, creating that quota requires individual landlords to take their units off the market, thus sacrificing any share of the surplus they might get.
They extract their surplus directly in the appreciation of vacant units. They can either hold that as a form of savings, or borrow using it as collateral if they need the cash flow, all without actually renting out the property.
"Nope. First come, first serve: a time-honored principle."
DeleteI mean here I agree: No, prospective tenants do not have a say.
That's a good question, in what sense is the anti-gentrification sentiment in SF "bad"? Certainly, it seems that people have the power to limit the housing supply, and this power is legitimate. However, I think it represents a misunderstanding of the consequences of their own policies, and also represents a selfishness that decreases the overall good.
ReplyDeleteFor example, there was recently an attempt to build luxury housing along the bay, which voters shut down because they wanted more affordable housing instead. Affordable housing is explicitly what they want, but they are using the wrong means to get it.
The policies also decrease the welfare of prospective tenants and people who move around a lot (most personally relevant, it affects students and the younger generation). Lastly, it represents defection in an inter-city prisoner's dilemma. For example, there were the "Google bus protests" which protested gentrification by Google employees, who commuted to Silicon Valley from SF. But the reason that those buses exist in the first place is because Silicon Valley has been even more effective than SF at limiting its own housing supply!
Rent control is not the source of all these problems, and I would not even argue that rent control is, on balance, a bad thing. But there's something messed up about local housing politics, and rent control seems to be a key component.
I don't exactly follow SF politics since I don't even live in the city, so I may have mischaracterized some of the details of the waterfront housing proposition. I believe that the one I'm talking about is proposition B.
DeleteI'm even further removed from the SF political scene than you. I don't think we can properly evaluate the role of rent control in SF without a more detailed analysis of the political-economic situation.
ReplyDeleteOn GP, I think SF is still gentrifying fast, and I don't see that anything (short of revolution) is going to stop it. Rent control at least slows the process down a bit, and gives some residents time to not have to make panic moves.